Skip to main content

Well-Designed, Fiscally Responsible Corporate Tax Reform Could Benefit the Economy: Unpaid-For Rate Cuts Would Likely Hurt Most Americans in the Long Run

Summary

Over the past year, proposals for federal corporate tax cuts and corporate tax reform have received increasing attention.  The corporate income tax appears to have joined the long list of tax issues likely to be addressed, or at least debated, over the next few years.

Already, two different approaches have emerged.  In October 2007, Ways and Means Committee Chair Charles Rangel introduced legislation that would significantly reduce the corporate tax rate and pay for the rate cut by eliminating several sizable corporate tax breaks.  While some applauded Rep. Rangel’s package as sensible tax reform, others have questioned the notion of paying for corporate rate cuts by scaling back corporate tax benefits.  For example, economist Glenn Hubbard, former chair of President Bush’s Council of Economic Advisers, wrote in a Wall Street Journal op-ed that “economically wise base-broadening alone is not likely to finance a significant corporate rate cut”[1] — that is, it would not be possible to finance a corporate rate cut of the desired magnitude through base-broadening measures without harming the economy.

The Bush Administration initially appeared to endorse the rate-reducing, base-broadening tax reform model embodied in Rep. Rangel’s proposal.  In July 2007, the Treasury Department issued a major report on business taxation that offered options for financing a corporate rate cut by eliminating corporate tax breaks.[2]  But in a December follow-up report, the Treasury commented, “it remains unclear whether a revenue-neutral reform would provide a reduction in business taxes sufficient to enhance the competitiveness of U.S. businesses.”[3]  The implication of this and other such statements is that the overall corporate tax burden, not just the statutory tax rate, needs to be lowered substantially and that paying for a rate cut with base broadening would reduce or eliminate its economic benefits.

Given the serious fiscal challenges the nation faces, it is fortunate that these claims are mistaken.  Far from being in conflict, fiscal responsibility and economic efficiency are complementary goals for corporate tax reform.  Reforms that eliminate inefficient tax subsidies and thereby raise revenue would also have the effect of leveling the playing field for different forms of investment, making the corporate income tax more economically efficient.

This analysis makes three main points.

  • U.S. corporate tax rates are lower, and the economic effects of the U.S. corporate income tax likely smaller, than is often suggested.  Some have claimed that the U.S. corporate tax rate is out of line with international norms and unduly burdens American businesses.  However, these critics typically focus only on the statutory marginal tax rate.  The Treasury Department, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), and other researchers have found that effective corporate tax rates — the share of the return on corporate investment that is actually paid in taxes — are far lower than the statutory rate and, depending on the category of investment, are similar to, only modestly higher than, or significantly lower than effective corporate tax rates in other developed countries.  As the Treasury Department explained, the United States has a high statutory rate but a low effective rate because of its “narrow corporate tax base,” which is the result of “accelerated depreciation allowances [and] special tax provisions for particular business sectors … as well as debt finance and tax planning.”[4]

    Moreover, while there is good reason to think that the corporate income tax has some economic costs, claims that it greatly harms the U.S. economy or significantly reduces U.S. wages rest on studies that are not applicable to the United States or that suffer from a number of other problems.  As the non-partisan Congressional Research Service (CRS) concluded in a recent report, “many of the concerns expressed about the corporate tax are not supported by empirical data…  Claims that high U.S. rates will create problems for the United States in a global economy suffer from a misrepresentation of the U.S. tax rate compared to other countries and are less important when capital is imperfectly mobile, as it appears to be.”[5]
  • Unpaid-for corporate rate cuts are unlikely to significantly help the economy; in fact, a Joint Committee on Taxation study found they could harm it.[6]  This could occur because the deficits and debt that result from unpaid-for tax cuts have negative economic effects, which can outweigh the economic benefits of the tax cuts themselves.  Furthermore, in the long run, deficit-financed tax cuts have to be paid for, either through increases in other taxes or through cuts to government services.  Given these eventual financing costs, unpaid-for corporate tax cuts would likely leave most Americans worse off in the long run, even if they generated modest economic benefits.
  • Large disparities in the treatment of different types of corporate investment create opportunities for reforms that could be revenue neutral — or even raise revenue — while at the same time improving economic efficiency.  The wide variation that exists today in corporate tax rates on different forms of investment creates economic distortions and inefficiency, since it encourages businesses to choose among investments based on their tax benefits instead of their real economic value.  Thus, reforming the corporate tax so as to equalize effective tax rates among different types of investment would likely have economic benefits.

    Such reform might involve lowering the statutory corporate rate while scaling back corporate tax breaks.  As Brookings Institution economist and Hamilton Project director Jason Furman has explained, “Both halves of this classic equation have the potential for helping the economy by eliminating the perverse incentives to invest in tax-favored activities rather than in more economically productive activities.”[7]

(21pp.)

End Notes

[1] R. Glenn Hubbard, “The Corporate Tax Myth,” Wall Street Journal, July 26, 2007.

[2] Treasury also considered the possibility of using base broadening to pay for partial expensing of corporate investment, an approach that could be highly problematic if not coupled with other changes; see the box on page 19.  U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Treasury Conference on Business Taxation and Global Competitiveness:  Background Paper,” July 23, 2007, http://www.treas.gov/press/releases/reports/07230%20r.pdf.

[3] Office of Tax Policy, U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Approaches to Improve the Competitiveness of the U.S. Business Tax System for the 21st Century,” December 20, 2007, http://www.ustreas.gov/press/releases/reports/hp749_approachesstudy.pdf.

[4] Office of Tax Policy, U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Approaches to Improve the Competitiveness of the U.S. Business Tax System for the 21st Century.”

[5] Jane G. Gravelle and Thomas L. Hungerford, “Corporate Tax Reform:  Issues for Congress,” Congressional Research Service, updated April 22, 2008.

[6] Joint Committee on Taxation, “Macroeconomic Analysis of Various Proposals to Provide $500 Billion in Tax Relief,” JCX-4-05, March 1, 2005, http://www.house.gov/jct/x-4-05.pdf.

[7] Jason Furman, “Corporate Taxes, in Need of Reform,” Washington Post, October 27, 2007, http://www.brookings.edu/opinions/2007/1027_corporate_taxes_furman.aspx.