June 27, 2002

Social Security and The Tax Cut:
A Response to the Concord Coalition
By Robert Greenstein, Richard Kogan, and Peter Orszag

PDF of this report

Social Security and the Tax Cut: HTML and PDF

Related Reports

If you cannot access the files through the links, right-click on the underlined text, click "Save Link As," download to your directory, and open the document in Adobe Acrobat Reader.

On June 18, 2002, the Concord Coalition issued a short discussion of a Center analysis initially issued last August and revised this April. The Center's analysis relied upon the Social Security actuaries' estimate of the size of the Social Security financing deficit, Congressional Budget Office estimates of the cost of the tax cut enacted last year (when the tax cut is phased in fully), and standard CBO and GAO methods for projecting the long-term effects of tax and spending policies. The Center's analysis found that if all elements of the tax cut are made permanent, the revenue loss from the tax cut will be more than twice as large over the next 75 years as the 75-year shortfall in the Social Security trust fund.(1) (Social Security's financial status is traditionally measured over a 75-year period.)

The Concord Coalition's short piece argued that this type of analysis sets back the cause of Social Security reform; it says that "defenders of the status quo take this [i.e., the Center's finding] to mean that all we need to do to fix Social Security is to scale back the tax cut." Concord stated that "Defenders of the status quo pose a false choice to the American public when they imply that all that's needed to fix Social Security is an open line to the Treasury."

In an initial version of this paper, Concord mistakenly implied that our analysis itself advocated such a course. This is not the case — our paper explicitly rejected such a course and stressed that Social Security reform is necessary — and Concord quickly revised its paper to correct this problem. But the Concord piece continues to challenge the analytic basis and usefulness of our comparison of the size of the tax cut to the size of the Social Security shortfall. As the follow discussion indicates, we believe the comparison is not only analytically sound but is helpful — rather than harmful — in advancing the causes of both fiscal responsibility and Social Security reform. Furthermore, we believe that in its zeal to counter any suggestion that scaling back the tax cut could substitute for Social Security reform, the Concord piece inadvertently made statements inconsistent with past Concord positions and current efforts to promote fiscal responsibility.

We should note at the outset that we are longstanding admirers of — and frequent collaborators with — Concord. In recent years, the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities and the Concord Coalition have jointly conducted a number of Congressional and media briefings and conferences on issues related to fiscal policy and fiscal responsibility. The concerns that underlie our analysis of the tax cut and the Social Security shortfall reflect this focus on the need for fiscal responsibility. The discussion that follows covers the following four points.

The Need for Social Security Reform

Concord's principal policy objection to the Center's analysis is that it believes "defenders of the status quo" will take our analysis to mean that Congress should repeal or scale back the tax cut, use the savings to ensure Social Security solvency, and make no changes in Social Security itself. We agree that such a course of action would be irresponsible; our analysis is explicit on this point. While noting that the Social Security shortfall over the next 75 years equals about 40 percent of the cost of the tax cut over the same period, our paper warns:

"We should emphasize that we would not recommend canceling 40 percent of the tax cut and placing all of the freed-up resources in Social Security. The nation will face serious financial strains when the baby boomers retire in large numbers. The long-term financing shortfall in Medicare is larger than that in Social Security, and the nation also is likely to face needs in the decades ahead that will require resources in other areas, including areas relating to children, the environment, the large number of Americans without health insurance, the lack of a Medicare prescription drug benefit, and the uncertain costs of homeland security, as well as other problems that inevitably will arise in the future but that we cannot foresee today. A balanced long-term fiscal policy is likely to entail some changes in Social Security to reduce its future claims on the budget, rather than simply providing it with whatever resources are needed from the rest of the budget to close its entire long-term financing shortfall. Providing resources from the rest of the budget to close a portion (rather than all) of the Social Security shortfall, however — in conjunction with other Social Security reforms — is likely to be essential if any reform plan to restore long-term solvency is to have hope of being enacted. Otherwise, the Social Security benefit cuts and payroll tax increases that will be required as part of any solvency plan are likely to be too large for such a plan to be politically viable" (emphasis added).

We emphasized in our paper that any savings generated by scaling back the tax cut should not simply be transferred in full to Social Security. There are many unmet needs, including saving for the future, that would warrant consideration as potential uses of the revenue saved by scaling back the tax cut. Moreover, some contribution to the long-term budget problem will necessarily have to come from Social Security itself. In a subsequent paper published by the Center, an analysis by economists Peter Diamond and Peter Orszag, we returned to this point. This paper labels as "fiscally reckless" the notion of simply closing the entire Social Security shortfall through general revenue transfers.(2)

The increases in the cost of Social Security benefits in future decades might not be unaffordable by themselves if there were no other pressures on the budget. CBO projects that the costs of Social Security will grow by 1.9 percent of GDP as the baby boomers retire and then level off. If the government were to pay off most of the debt held by the public so that it no longer had to pay significant interest on the debt (currently running at 1.7 percent of GDP), the interest savings by themselves would almost cover the increase in the costs of Social Security. But there are many other pressures on the budget, in addition to Social Security. The combined costs of Medicare and Medicaid will grow from 3.4 percent of GDP in 2000 to 15.2 percent of GDP in 2075, according to CBO.(3) In addition, there are other national needs that are not currently being met. A key problem with the tax cut, which Concord has emphasized in other contexts, is that it makes it much harder to repay debt and reduce these interest costs in anticipation of these large demographic pressures.

The Tax Cut, General Revenue Transfers, and Social Security Solvency

The Concord piece suggests that comparing the cost of the tax cut to the Social Security shortfall is dangerous: people will use the comparison to defend the Social Security status quo, Concord fears, making Social Security reform harder to achieve.

This could occur. But we believe that analyses such as ours are more likely to facilitate Social Security reform than to impede it.

Targeted general revenue transfers to Social Security can be accomplished. Since 1983, a portion of federal income tax receipts has been transferred each year to the Social Security Trust Fund. (These income tax receipts are generated by counting a portion of Social Security benefits as taxable income for higher-income beneficiaries.) Congress could follow a similar course by, for example, reforming rather than repealing the estate tax and dedicating a specified portion of the preserved estate tax revenues to the Social Security Trust Fund. The Kolbe-Stenholm bill also contains a proposal of this type: it would index federal benefit and tax code provisions currently tied to the Consumer Price Index by a measure that rises more slowly than the CPI and then transfer all resulting savings to the Social Security Trust Fund each year.

In its June 18 paper, Concord seems to object to such an approach; it appears to argue against using any general fund revenue to help restore Social Security solvency. That position is both impractical — as noted, no reform plan that lacks any general revenue transfers appears even to be discussable — and is inconsistent with past Concord positions in praising proposals such as the Kolbe-Stenholm plan that include some general revenue transfers. In any case, we believe that while general revenue transfers should be neither the entire nor the principal part of plans to restore Social Security solvency, limited general fund transfers are essential to facilitate Social Security reform.

"No practical significance"?

The Concord paper contends that a comparison of the cost of the tax cut to the size of the Social Security shortfall "is of no practical significance." There are, however, at least two practical reasons for making such a comparison.

Analytic Issues

The Concord piece raises analytic concerns about the method we use of comparing the cost of the tax cut to the size of the Social Security shortfall. Concord argues that what matters is Social Security's annual cash-flow balance, not its 75-year actuarial balance. The Concord piece consequently criticizes our comparison of the total cost of the Social Security shortfall over 75 years to the total cost of the tax cut.

The Center's comparison of the long-term Social Security shortfall and the cost of the tax cut follows standard and widely accepted methods in the field for measuring and comparing long-term costs. The principal measure that the highly respected Office of the Chief Actuary at the Social Security Administration uses to evaluate Social Security reform proposals is not the effect of such proposals on the program's annual cash flow balances, but rather their effect on the program's 75-year actuarial balance. The figures provided in the Center's analysis for the size of the Social Security shortfall are the widely used 75-year shortfall figures taken directly from the most recent report of the Social Security actuaries and trustees. (It also may be noted that the Social Security actuaries have concluded the best way to express the long-term Social Security imbalance in dollar terms is to present the imbalance in terms of its "present value." This is what our analysis does, using the actuaries' estimates.)

Similarly, in estimating the long-term cost of the tax cut, we used the standard methodology that CBO and GAO employ in projecting the long-term costs of tax and spending policies. We use CBO and Joint Committee on Taxation estimates of the cost of the tax cut in 2011 if all of the provisions of the tax cut are extended. We then use the standard method that CBO and GAO use in their long-term budget forecasts, which is to assume that such costs will remain constant in future decades as a share of the Gross Domestic Product. We also express the long-term costs of the tax cut both as a share of GDP and in "present value." This, too, is the standard practice that CBO and GAO have followed. It also is the approach typically used by prominent fiscal policy experts, such as Alan Auerbach of the University of California at Berkeley and William Gale of the Brookings Institution.

Saving for the Future

Concord also raises a second, and more important, point here. It argues that scaling back the tax cut would be of no help to Social Security unless the preserved revenues are saved rather than quickly spent. Concord sees a risk that if the tax cut were scaled back, none of the savings would be retained for the future. Instead, all of the savings might be used for other current needs.

This is the most significant issue the Concord piece raises. The tax cut itself is evidence for the proposition that it is politically hard to save for the future. Yet "throwing in the towel" — and concluding that it is impossible to preserve savings achieved by scaling back the tax cut or instituting spending reductions — is premature. It also is inconsistent with the work and pronouncements over the years of the Concord Coalition itself, which has striven mightily to build surpluses.


End Notes:

1. Richard Kogan, Robert Greenstein, and Peter Orszag, "Social Security and the Tax Cut: The 75-Year Cost of the Tax Cut Is More than Twice as Large as the Long-Term Deficit in Social Security" Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, updated April 11, 2002, based on this year's report of the Social Security trustees; available at https://www.cbpp.org/4-9-02socsec.pdf.

2. The paper by Diamond and Orszag states: "A claim of long-term [Social Security] balance that is heavily dependent on substantial, unspecified general revenue transfers, however, raises questions of credibility....Congress could erase the long-term deficit in Social Security without any other changes simply by legislating that the Trust Fund would be able to draw upon general revenue as needed to finance scheduled benefits. If no other budget changes were made, such legislation would raise serious questions about how the general revenue transfers could be financed when the need arrived....Given the current budget outlook, simply assuming the availability of such large transfers is highly problematic and could be regarded as fiscally reckless." Peter A. Diamond and Peter R. Orszag, "Reducing Benefits and Subsidizing Individual Accounts: An Analysis of the Plans Proposed by the President's Commission to Strengthen Social Security," Center on Budget and Policy Priorities and The Century Foundation, June 2002.

3. See "A 125-year picture of the Federal Government's Share of the Economy, 1950 to 2075," CBO, June 14, 2002.

4. See, for example, "The Cost of the Tax Cut Compared With the Costs of Various Federal Agencies," Center on Budget, April 17, 2002.

5. See, for example, "Don't Squander the Surplus: Reform Social Security and Medicare First," Concord Coalition, Aug 15, 1999.